98
views
0
recommends
+1 Recommend
1 collections
    0
    shares

      If you have found this article useful and you think it is important that researchers across the world have access, please consider donating, to ensure that this valuable collection remains Open Access.

      Prometheus is published by Pluto Journals, an Open Access publisher. This means that everyone has free and unlimited access to the full-text of all articles from our international collection of social science journalsFurthermore Pluto Journals authors don’t pay article processing charges (APCs).

      scite_
       
      • Record: found
      • Abstract: found
      • Article: found
      Is Open Access

      The ‘ownership’ of science

      Published
      research-article
      a , * , , a , a , a
      Prometheus
      Pluto Journals
      Bookmark

            Abstract

            Dr Catherine Rhodes is a research fellow at the Institute for Science, Ethics and Innovation specialising in the international regulations relevant to control of biotechnology. Professor John Harris is director of the Institute and has particular interest in biomedical ethics and medical jurisprudence. Sarah Chan is deputy director of the Institute. Professor Sir John Sulston was the founding director of the Wellcome Trust Sanger Centre in Cambridge from 1992 to 2000, where so much of the sequencing of the human genome was completed in a furious race to publish before American commercial interests patented. He was awarded the Nobel Prize in 2002.

            Main article text

            Prologue

            We are interested in the growing importance of intellectual property rights (IPR) and effects, both positive and negative, of IPR on the progress of science and innovation. The first section of this proposition paper is a consensus document, the Manchester Manifesto, produced by a working group meeting at the Institute for Science, Ethics and Innovation at the University of Manchester. The document elicited a variety of responses, including an exchange with the Chartered Institute of Patent Attorneys. A review of these forms the second section of the paper.

            The Manchester Manifesto is not anti-IPR, but it does ask to what extent IPR are helpful in the delivery of important public goods and services that are essential for human flourishing, and what changes should be made to correct any shortcomings. This is not the first, and certainly will not be the last, discussion of the merits of IPR. Debates are often highly polarised, as can be judged below, but we hope that the responses in Prometheus will lead to a broadening of the dialogue – particularly on how to move towards more appropriate management of innovation.

            Because IPR lie at the heart of the ‘knowledge society’, there is a widespread unwillingness to consider any problems, and indeed great resistance to any suggestion that reform is needed. Furthermore, it is frequently said that strengthening IPR is always good and is essential for promoting innovation. Some evidence points the other way. For example, the first green revolution, which averted mass starvation for a generation, was conducted in the public domain, motivated by goodwill, and its products were distributed freely. In contrast, it is unclear whether the much-needed second green revolution will be as successful, if it becomes bogged down in conflicting IPR claims and leads to expensive products.

            The existing IPR system was built on exchanges between knowledgeable and consenting trading partners on a fairly level playing field, under which circumstance it served a useful purpose. However, it has subsequently grown unchecked without serious examination of the effects. Notably, in a highly unequal world, the existing system exacerbates inequities in health and wealth, so that the fruits of science are enjoyed mainly by the rich. Further, despite its merits on a small scale among well-matched trading partners, a strong IPR system is unhelpful for the massive global problems that we collectively face in resource limitations and climate change. These are zero sum games in which aggressive competitiveness is counterproductive.

            We appreciate that necessary reform of the IPR system will not take place on a unilateral basis, and will need collective efforts from all actors involved in the innovation process to ensure that science can fulfil its potential for promoting human flourishing and respond to major global challenges. This cannot be done without addressing the issues of inequity that are inherent in the current system. We cannot afford to allow innovation to remain overwhelmingly concentrated in a few developed nations. It was for this reason that the Institute for Science, Ethics and Innovation (2009) published the Manchester Manifesto.1

            The Manchester Manifesto

            Science, along with the innovation it generates, is a vast enterprise: commercial and pro-bono, public and private, industrial and educational, amateur and professional. It permeates our lives and shapes the world. Some say it is a defining characteristic of humanity, stimulating and harnessing our innate curiosity and, more than any other endeavour, shaping our world and, increasingly, ourselves.

            For many reasons, some of which are set out below, it is increasingly important to consider the question of “Who Owns Science?”. The answer to this question will have broad-ranging implications: for scientific progress, for equity of access to scientific knowledge and its fruits and for the fair distribution of the benefits and the burdens of science and innovation – in short, for global justice and human progress.

            Our approach

            The Manchester Manifesto Group brings together international experts from relevant disciplines to address the question of “Who Owns Science?” Led by two research institutes at The University of Manchester, the Institute for Science, Ethics and Innovation and the Brooks World Poverty Institute, chaired by John Sulston and Joseph Stiglitz, respectively, the Group represents a critical mass of research expertise that are ideally equipped to meet the challenges and problems outlined above. The Group’s members are drawn from a broad range of academic disciplines and relevant sectors, including economics, science, innovation, law, philosophy, ethics and public policy. Our goal has been not only to investigate the question of “Who Owns Science?” but to present and apply our findings to maximum effect in order to make a difference in the real world as to how science is used, and hence to “build a better future for humanity”.

            Statement of the problem

            Science is a rapidly growing industry. Beyond basic research, the commercialisation of technologies and development of new products from bench top to marketplace is a complex process. In asking “Who Owns Science?”, we are concerned with all aspects of this process: scientific discovery, development, application and distribution; and the interactions between each aspect. The way in which this is managed, and in particular the way in which access to technologies is facilitated and controlled, is having and will inevitably have an increasing impact on the course of science-based technological innovation.

            An important component of the innovation process has been the idea of “ownership” in science and technology. This concept has arisen partly in the context of profiting from research and development, but also has implications for much broader issues such as control of and access to scientific information and products that result from research, in terms of both the private and socio-political dimensions of ownership.

            To manage the ownership of science and the fruits of research, an intricate system of intellectual property (IP) law has developed. The justifications for IP law as it exists at present include the idea that it is required in order to facilitate scientific and economic benefit from innovation, and that it provides a fair and morally justifiable way of rewarding those who invest in the process of discovery and regulating access to these benefits.

            The initial meetings of the Manchester Manifesto Group in 2008–2009 established that the current method of managing innovation (and perhaps in particular IP in its present form), whilst deeply embedded in current practice and hence of practical importance, also has significant drawbacks in terms of its effects on science and economic efficiency, and raises ethical issues because of its (often adverse) effects on people and populations.

            The Manchester Manifesto Group considered the core goals of science and identified various issues and problems with the current system of ownership and management of science and innovation, highlighting elements that hinder or obstruct achievement of these goals. Reflecting on these problems, we were able to articulate some broad principles and policy considerations to guide any investigation or evaluation of alternative systems of innovation. Finally, we outlined some questions that must be addressed if we are to move towards solutions to the problems identified by the group. We call for further research in these areas as a matter of great importance, in order to answer the question not only of “Who Owns Science?”, but of who ought to own science and how the goals of science can best be fulfilled.

            Goals, Problems and Issues in Science and Innovation

            Goals
            Science and the public good

            Science can serve the public good by generating knowledge to meet human needs and purposes. This includes knowledge with direct application to current challenges and pure/undirected endeavour (so called “blue skies” research) that forms the essential basis for future scientific discovery.

            • The pursuit of pure (unapplied) scientific research is clearly in the public interest, since curiosity expands knowledge, which is in itself a good thing. This justifies investment in such research.

            • Science-based technological innovation further serves the public good by playing a key role in economic growth and development.

            • There is a basic public interest in access to knowledge.

            Innovation and the public good

            Management of innovation has significant implications for scientific progress and human welfare. It affects the distribution of benefits, access to technology, dissemination of knowledge, and the pace and direction of research.

            • Innovation should operate for the public good, amongst other goals.

            • Given their efforts and investments, the scientific community and the public can also be viewed as ‘shareholders’ in innovation, and its benefits should remain open to them (in the form of welfare goods and knowledge).

            Reciprocal responsibilities of science and society

            The relationship between science and society is essentially one of reciprocity, mutual benefit, and needs to be seen to be so. Just as science has responsibilities to the public good, the public has responsibilities towards science as the collective recipient of its benefits and as a major funder of its activities – a relationship that is often mediated by policy:

            • Public confidence in and engagement with science is vital; openness to public scrutiny can help to maintain trust and support. Science should be open to the public, enabling understanding of its purposes and implications.

            • Society needs to provide just and effective conditions for the increase of scientific knowledge. Any management mechanisms should be justifiable, appropriate, and built on a sound understanding of both science and the systems in which it operates.

            • To achieve the goals of promoting scientific progress and human welfare, the scientific community has a responsibility to facilitate reflection of scientific understanding in policy, and should seek participation in policy-making processes and debates at the national and international level.

            • Policy-makers need to ensure that there are opportunities for voices from the scientific community to be heard. Scientists and policy-makers have a joint responsibility to ensure this participation occurs in a transparent manner to avoid public suspicion of undue influence.

            • Policy-makers should also ensure that there are opportunities for the voices of the public to be heard.

            Issues/Problems in the Current Management of Innovation

            The interests and contributions of inventors and authors deserve to be recognised fairly. However the current dominant model of innovation and commercialisation of science poses a number of problems. It has potential to encourage innovation and stimulate research and development, but also to frustrate innovation and stifle research and development; and can hinder science from operating in a way consistent with the public good.

            Access to benefits of research

            Current models can restrict or prevent public access to the benefits of research – both the information generated by scientific endeavour and the products of innovation based on that science – and thereby hinder science from serving the public good.

            • Certain licensing and commercial practices can restrict access to the products of science and innovation, particularly for those with limited market power.

            • This is of particular concern in the case of those products that address basic needs (such as health care).

            • The current model rewards particular kinds of creative effort, namely those which result in commercial gain. It is therefore likely to hinder innovation of products that have limited market value, but which may have huge social benefit.

            • The obligation on corporate innovation to maximise profit and return for shareholders can conflict with the creation of knowledge and achievement of welfare goals.

            Effect on innovation

            Current models can hinder innovation because:

            • Certain licensing practices can have restrictive effects on innovation. These include, for example, use of very narrow or exclusive licence terms.

            • The increasingly common incidence of requiring multiple licences for the use of a single technology or research tool complicates access, making it more costly and time-consuming.

            • Perceptions of accessibility problems can lead to enterprises deciding not to attempt to apply for licences.

            • New business entry into innovative industries is very difficult due to the high transaction costs involved in operating in an arena of multiple intellectual property rights, reducing competition and allowing large companies to dominate markets.

            • Navigation and implementation of the patent system, negotiation, bargaining and litigation require costly expertise.

            • The operation of the current system often prevents the holders of IP rights themselves from realising the full benefits of these rights, for example because of the costs involved in asserting them.

            Scientific progress

            • Restrictions on access to information at any stage of the innovative process obstruct the flow of scientific information and thereby impede scientific progress. Such restrictions are also contrary to the needs of scientific inquiry and are inimical to openness and transparency.

            • Information sharing among the scientific community can be reduced or suffer from delays as a result of patent requirements (e.g. that information must not be in the public domain at time of filing).

            • The complexity of the system creates uncertainty, for example over researchers’ ability to obtain necessary licences, which can discourage investment in research and development.

            • These access restrictions have particularly severe effects on public, not-for-profit, small and developing country enterprises, which cannot afford the expense of licences and/or the expertise required to navigate the patent system. This can obstruct, delay, or entirely shut-down valuable lines of research and innovation.

            Overall, the current patent system is self-reinforcing, encouraging proliferation of patents and multiplying these problems.

            Broader Issues

            There are also broader issues resulting from the dominant model of innovation which should be given consideration.

            • Improving systems of innovation may not be enough in itself to promote human welfare; there is also the problem of insufficient capacity, particularly in many developing countries, to access scientific information, operate and navigate innovation systems, and achieve access to innovative products e.g. because of weak health infrastructure.

            • The transition from basic science to product in the clinic or marketplace is not always linear and unidirectional. The relationship between ‘pure’ and ‘applied’ research, science, technology and innovation is a complex and multi-faceted one, with interactions between actors at all stages influencing the process. The effects of action/regulation in one area may have implications extending across other aspects, and each area may have unique issues and problems associated with its management.

            • Within this process, actors can have multiple roles, creating potential conflicts of interest. For example, a single individual may have both scientific and commercial interests at stake; governments may face a conflict between stimulating economic development through rewarding private investment in research and optimising the public benefits of science.

            • In many cases, profit has become the primary reward for research and development – often to the point of other drivers of innovation dropping out of consideration. Greater consideration should be given to different drivers of science/incentives for innovation beyond profit.

            • It is not only the intellectual property system that restricts participation in innovation; there is also all too often a lack of strategies to encourage openness of communication, participation in research, and sharing of information and products that result from science and innovation.

            Global Dynamics

            The global context in which science and innovation now operate and of which they are an integral part needs to be given consideration, because it also affects their operation and effectiveness.

            While states have the sovereign right to adopt their own rules, laws and procedures, they need to operate within the bounds of a variety of international rules and norms and with awareness of international dynamics. For management of innovation, these include:

            • Permeable national boundaries creating high mobility of knowledge, materials, and personnel, and meaning that the impacts of national policies may be widely felt in other states.

            • In areas which lack harmonised international regulation, innovative activities can migrate to territories in which regulatory regimes are weak or non-existent.

            • Frequent prioritisation of national interest and economic competitiveness by states in their international relations.

            • Wide disparities between rich and poor within and between states, in terms of income, opportunities, health, education, and access to science, technology and the products of innovation.

            International regulation has advantages in its ability to harmonise national policies, providing clarity and reducing the costs of compliance. It must be recognised, however, that international regulation also has disadvantages. Powerful states have greater influence in rule-setting and less to fear in regard to the consequences of non-compliance. Commitments to capacity-building for developing states are inadequately fulfilled and enforcement is problematic.

            Additional problems occur at the international level:

            • Diverse national regulation of innovation creates complexity in compliance. This can increase costs to innovators, pushing publicly funded, not-for-profit and developing country enterprises out of international markets.

            • International regulation can have the effect of privileging the interests of wealthy states over general human needs due to power imbalances.

            • International regulation currently remains state focused and often reinforces state sovereign rights. It can therefore be of limited effect on transnational actors (e.g. corporations) and often promotes national interest above that of local communities.

            • Bilateral agreements and ‘free trade areas’ are being used to impose excessive and inappropriate standards on less developed countries.

            The effect of the current international rules, which set minimum standards for intellectual property protection, is that a single model of intellectual property protection dominates, and at the same time is operative in many national systems. This dominant model is intended to promote scientific and economic development, but can be radically flawed in this respect. Alternative models need to be promoted and existing flexibilities fully explored to ensure innovation can meet welfare goals.

            Principles, Policy Considerations and Progress

            We recognise that innovation has an essential role in economic development, but its use for the pursuit of profit should not override, and ideally should not conflict with, achievement of welfare goals and scientific progress. Scientific information, freely and openly communicated, adds to the body of knowledge and understanding upon which the progress of humanity depends. Information must remain available to science and this depends on open communication and dissemination of information, including that used in innovation.

            Management of innovation is one of the routes through which public benefits of science can be realised. This requires a range of appropriate policies and regulatory mechanisms developed in cooperation with scientists, innovators and the public, combined with awareness of the implications of pursuing particular models of innovation management.

            Advantages and disadvantages of these models need to be carefully assessed in regard to their cumulative impacts on the innovative process, achievement of welfare goals and scientific progress. Current systems for managing innovation may require adaptation and incorporation of greater flexibilities. In addition, consideration of alternative systems is needed.

            Principles

            The regulation of frameworks of innovation should promote the following objectives:

            • Provision of public benefit

            • Just recognition of interests

            • Facilitating progress of science and innovation

            • Increasing access to fruits of research – information and products

            • Addressing welfare and resource inequities both locally and globally

            • Increasing trust in the relationships between scientists, innovators, corporations and public, and between nations

            At times these objectives may conflict and attention must be given to the most appropriate way of balancing them in each situation.

            Policy Considerations
            Alternative systems

            The current dominant model of intellectual property rights for innovation is not the only option available. There are existing alternatives and new models can be designed with differing cost distributions. Different systems may be appropriate in different areas; consideration must be given to the factors that affect this, including the nature of the knowledge, the method of discovery and the environment in which knowledge generation takes place.

            For example, the current system can be modified through increased use of mechanisms such as patent pools, voluntary or compulsory licensing, and differential pricing. A range of alternative models is also possible: from those which are related to the current rights system such as remuneration-based patents, through prize funds, to completely open-access models.

            Assessing models of innovation

            Any model of innovation is likely to have advantages and disadvantages. Consideration should be given to which is the most appropriate for particular circumstances, bearing in mind the principles above and the goals of science and innovation.

            In evaluating the various possible models, the following factors should be taken into consideration:

            • The extent to which it advances welfare and promotes human flourishing

            • Fair and equitable distribution of benefits and burdens, with particular attention to resource providers (including the scientific community, the public, specific contributors of knowledge/biomaterials, and other contributors)

            • Facilitation of safe and sustainable access to the end product

            • Affordability in use of the system and of the end products

            • Maintenance of free flow of scientific information

            • Promotion of open communication

            • The provision of adequate incentives to stimulate scientific discovery and innovation

            • Ease and effectiveness of operation

            • Inclusion of operational rules appropriate to achieving desired objectives

            • Awareness of global dynamics

            Principles and Progress in the Global Context

            The objectives for innovation management listed earlier also need to be achieved within the global context. Design and choice of innovation model may also, therefore, need to take into account the issues raised in the discussion of Global Dynamics.

            Conclusions

            We have considered the question of “Who Owns Science” in the context of what we believe to be the purposes of science and innovation and evaluated the way in which ownership of science currently operates with respect to these purposes. It is clear that the dominant existing model of innovation, while serving some necessary purposes for the current operation of innovation, also impedes achievement of core scientific goals in a number of ways. In many cases it restricts access to scientific knowledge and products, thereby limiting the public benefits of science; it can restrict the flow of information, thereby inhibiting the progress of science; and it may hinder innovation through the costly and complicated nature of the system. Limited improvements may be achieved through modification of the current IP system, but consideration of alternative models is urgently required.

            We call for further research towards achieving more equitable innovation and enabling greater fulfilment of the goals of science as we see them.

            Modified and alternative models of innovation have the potential to address problems inherent in the current system. An investigation and evaluation of these models is required in order to determine whether they are likely to be more successful in facilitating the goals of science and innovation identified above, and if so how they may be deployed. Greater cooperation between all actors is required; alongside development of theory, there is a clear need for practical engagement with actors at all stages of the innovation process.

            The scope of this document is largely concerned with science that is in the public interest. More thought must be given to how we characterise what sort of science is in the public interest, and how we draw the boundaries between “public” and “private” science, in both the practical and the normative sense.

            Members of the Manchester Manifesto Group have been actively pursuing research initiatives in these important areas; and the Group remains the base for practical discussion and ongoing investigations. We hope that the Manchester Manifesto will serve as a starting point for discussion, reflection and further research on these issues amongst all those concerned and involved with science and innovation.

            Epilogue – responses

            The Manchester Manifesto attracted considerable interest and comment, some supportive, some critical (see, in particular, Brice, 2009; Prowse, 2009; Wild, 2009; Worstall, 2009). Here, we review and respond to some of the more generic comments (see also Sulston et al., 2009; Harris et al., 2010).

            Knowledge sharing is fundamental to the operation of the IPR system

            Although publication is ultimately part of the patent system, the climate of secrecy it can promote is not conducive to knowledge sharing, in advance of patenting at least. The requirement for novelty discourages knowledge sharing at the pre-filing stage. The expectation of patents means that many institutions have strict rules about publication and even talking to people; for example, the University of Manchester’s own guidance advises: ‘If you think your invention is potentially patentable it is essential that the details of the invention are kept secret until the application for the patent is made’. This clearly discourages the sharing of information that would otherwise occur as part of the scientific process.

            Post-patent, even automatic publication does not guarantee usable access to the information. Although the data may nominally be available once published through the patent system, we believe that data from these sources is often incomplete and must be deciphered by an expert. It would be useful, in fact, to know the average value of such data compared with other forms of publication; and this is part of the challenge issued by the Manchester Manifesto.

            Compulsory licensing provisions in patent rules mean that it is not possible to use patents to obstruct products from reaching markets

            In practice, fears of sanctions mean that compulsory licenses are rarely used, and the effect of the system is still to deny access to products to those who need them (Odell-West, 2009; t’Hoen, 2009).

            Patenting provides financial benefits to universities. Their research is not restricted because patent rules provide for experimental use exemptions

            This may be true in theory, but it is not always or even often the case in practice. Because universities are being pushed to do more commercial or pre-commercial work, it is often unclear whether the research exemption will apply. The threat of an infringement action itself, even if ultimately unfounded, may deter research. Moreover, the experimental use exemption in some jurisdictions is very narrow and this affects the global research climate. For most universities, the returns from patenting are very modest, and do not cover the full opportunity costs incurred. Even were this not the case, our point is that such returns should be foregone in the public interest.

            Some say that IPR blocks access to essential medicines, but investment in research and development for these drugs would collapse without it

            The Manchester Manifesto recognises that IPR currently play an important role in the financing of research and development, and that since this system is international, no one actor can unilaterally alter it. All the more reason, then, to look critically at the innovation system as a whole and to ask whether it is functioning optimally. While politics and economics may be the driving forces that block access to drugs and prevent participation in innovation, IPR law provides the tools that enable this to happen. Without these, politics would be not nearly as effective in denying anti-retroviral drugs to African populations, or in denying developing countries access to knowledge. Of course, this can be accomplished by other means as well, but this is no reason to provide the tools and even encourage their use to perpetrate injustice.

            There are two different issues at stake here: first, affordability of existing innovation; second, incentives for further innovation. The IPR system is a tool for encouraging innovation for drugs for rich markets, but this mechanism does nothing about affordability, leading to the problems of access described. In the absence of a rich market, the IPR tool is of no help in creating incentives to discover and manufacture drugs, leading to the problem of neglected diseases for which the necessary investment to discover and manufacture drugs is lacking. Mechanisms to increase affordability, such as patent pools, and alternative incentives for innovation, such as prize funds, are needed to address these problems.

            Notes

            References

            1. Brice, P. (2009) ‘Who owns science: questionable critique of IP system’, PHG Foundation News, 17 December, available from http://www.phgfoundation.org/news/5086/ [accessed November 2010].

            2. Harris, J., Chan, S., and Sulston J. (2010) Responses, available from http://www.isei.manchester.ac.uk/themanchestermanifesto/responses/ [accessed December 2010].

            3. Institute for Science, Ethics and Innovation (2009) Who Owns Science? The Manchester Manifesto, available from http://www.isei.manchester.ac.uk/TheManchesterManifesto.pdf [accessed November 2010].

            4. Odell-West A.. 2009. . The legacy of Myriad for gene-based diagnostics: a new policy and regulatory option. . Journal of Intellectual Property Law and Practice . , Vol. 4:: 267––277. .

            5. Prowse, P. (2009) Patent Profession Welcomes Manchester Manifesto On Science But Slams ‘Misleading’ Comments On IP, Chartered Institute of Patent Attorneys, available from http://www.cipa.org.uk/pages/press/article?D5C2CBED-894B-488B-ACD2-07B01E204A06 [accessed November 2010].

            6. Sulston J., Chan S. and Harris J.. 2009. . How science is shackled by intellectual property. . Guardian . ,

            7. t’Hoen E.. 2009. . The Global Politics of Pharmaceutical Monopoly Power . , Diemen : : AMB Publishers. .

            8. Wild, J. (2009) ‘The Manchester Manifesto and the IP world’s failure to communicate’, Intellectual Asset Management Magazine, 30 November, available from http://www.iam-magazine.com/blog/Detail.aspx?g=591e8d58-0f0c-40d8-88d6-287a2403ce01 [accessed October 2011].

            9. Worstall, T. (2009) ‘Who owns science? Manchester Manifesto can’t answer’, Register, 4 December, available from http://www.theregister.co.uk/2009/12/04/manchester_manifesto/ [accessed November 2010].

            Footnotes

            1. The Manchester Manifesto was first published in November 2009 by the University of Manchester and is available at http://www.isei.manchester.ac.uk/TheManchesterManifesto.pdf. It is republished here with permission. The list of signatories is provided on p. 7 of the Manifesto.

            Author and article information

            Contributors
            Journal
            cpro20
            CPRO
            Prometheus
            Critical Studies in Innovation
            Pluto Journals
            0810-9028
            1470-1030
            September 2011
            : 29
            : 3
            : 325-336
            Affiliations
            a Institute for Science, Ethics and Innovation, University of Manchester , UK
            Author notes
            Article
            631272 Prometheus, Vol. 29, No. 3, September 2011, 325–336
            10.1080/08109028.2011.631272
            9a8cf9da-20ee-4189-b59c-75cd22e5e81f
            Copyright Taylor & Francis Group, LLC

            All content is freely available without charge to users or their institutions. Users are allowed to read, download, copy, distribute, print, search, or link to the full texts of the articles in this journal without asking prior permission of the publisher or the author. Articles published in the journal are distributed under a http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

            History
            Page count
            Figures: 0, Tables: 0, References: 9, Pages: 12
            Categories
            Proposition

            Computer science,Arts,Social & Behavioral Sciences,Law,History,Economics

            Comments

            Comment on this article