141
views
0
recommends
+1 Recommend
1 collections
    0
    shares

      If you have found this article useful and you think it is important that researchers across the world have access, please consider donating, to ensure that this valuable collection remains Open Access.

      Prometheus is published by Pluto Journals, an Open Access publisher. This means that everyone has free and unlimited access to the full-text of all articles from our international collection of social science journalsFurthermore Pluto Journals authors don’t pay article processing charges (APCs).

      scite_
       
      • Record: found
      • Abstract: found
      • Article: found
      Is Open Access

      Industrial organization of high technology markets. The internet and information technologies

      book-review
      a , *
      Prometheus
      Pluto Journals
      Bookmark

            Main article text

            Readers familiar with the economic literature on innovation and technological change will be disappointed if they search Industrial Organization of High Technology Markets for a definition of high technology along the lines proposed by the Frascati Manual (OECD, 2002). The authors use a different definition in relating high technology markets to the ‘main economic aspects related to Information and Communication Technologies’. Do not get me wrong, the contribution of the book is still valuable: there have been few good books on this subject since the path-breaking Information Rules (Shapiro and Varian, 1999). Shy (2001) and Belleflamme and Peitz (2010) are honourable exceptions. Standard economic texts have examined (in later versions) the impact of these high technology markets on industrial organization (Tirole, 1990) or business economics (Varian, 1990). What encourages the reader to use this book is that it introduces different key concepts in the area of network economics. These are generally not discussed in the traditional literature and include such concepts as the pace of innovation and technological change, and role of government intervention (anti-trust and regulation) in facilitating progress in network industries. A key issue not addressed in the book is how radical innovations which have come from other sectors are developing in these industries.

            The book contains eight chapters based on papers the two authors have published in a variety of journals in the area of industrial organization and the economics of innovation and technological change. In the introductory chapter, the authors define information and communication (ICT) industries in terms of four characteristics: large economies of scale, presence of network effects, high innovation rates, and substantial switching costs. These characteristics are the reason – according to the authors – that market efficiency is not achieved in digital markets. For example, the presence of large economies of scale leads to a market situation in which prices do not converge to marginal cost of production: ‘if they do, companies cannot compensate the fixed costs they incur’ (p.8). The authors go on to pose an interesting question: ‘Why are digital markets so far from efficiency despite satisfying many of the conditions required for perfect competition to emerge?’ (p.18). This question is interesting as a common assumption in the area of digital markets has been that market efficiency will improve if more and more companies provide their products and services online. Based on examining the Varian (1980) model of sales, the authors conclude that even if search costs are negligible in digital markets, price dispersion will remain a long-lasting phenomenon because of commercial strategies of retailers which lead to less market transparency among consumers. In addition, the authors examine the strategic behaviour of firms in digital markets aimed at achieving substantial market power using price discrimination, bundling and versioning, as well as pricing conditioned by purchase history. They conclude that firms are able to use more sophisticated pricing strategies on the Internet, which allow them to price discriminate more efficiently and to identify consumer preferences better.

            The authors connect the literature on path dependency with research in industrial organization on network externalities, lock-in effects and switching costs. For a long time, both strands of literature have progressed unrelated to each other with the first strand rooted in the Nelson and Winter tradition of modelling technological change (Nelson and Winter, 1982), and the second strand examining the interrelatedness of demand (Artle and Averous, 1973; Rohlfs, 1974). In the first tradition, the authors reflect on Arthur’s model of path dependency and the problems related to inefficient adoption of new technologies, such as the QWERTY keyboard (David, 1985; Arthur, 1989). Unfortunately, Comino and Manenti do not provide further insights; for example, on the role of government in this process [the ‘blind giant dilemma’ (David, 1987)] or when technologies which lock-in are actually good enough in terms of the knowledge of the time (Liebowitz and Margolis, 1994). Switching costs are briefly discussed, but their positive effects and the role of providers are omitted (Weizsäcker, 1984).

            Chapter 4 develops some surprising arguments about the consumer benefits of two-sided markets and discusses the emergence of dominant positions in these markets. It proposes that consumer benefits in two-sided markets can be larger (if there are highly asymmetric intensities of cross-side effects) under monopoly than in perfect competition. They go on to postulate that ‘fiercer competition may actually hurt consumers’ (p.117). There follows an interesting discussion of new concepts in the area of telecommunication economics and regulation of one-way access, such as Martin Cave’s ‘ladder of investment’ theory, and of two-way access in ‘receiving party pays’ (RPP) regimes. Again, the authors develop some surprising results with respect to one-way access pricing – ‘the incumbent benefits from competition in the downstream segment of the market’ (p.135) – which contradict some of the traditional literature on monopoly pricing. Unfortunately, the chapter ends just when it becomes interesting, when it starts to critique ladder of investment theory and begins a critical examination of the introduction of RPP regimes in Europe.

            The authors provide new insights into the ex ante incentives of innovators to invest in new research projects under different patent regimes (no protection and weak patents). In building on the literature on the role of the patent and trademark office (PTO) in granting patent protection, the authors conclude that a weak patent regime is socially desirable when the innovator already has large enough incentives to develop true innovation (p.201). What seems to be missing, even in the chapter entitled ‘Cumulative innovation in dynamic industries’, is any discussion of the dynamics in these industries.

            The authors reflect on the growing research on open source software (OSS) communities. They provide a focused explanation of a particular aspect in the literature – the circumstances under which an open core strategy is more socially beneficial than proprietary software. The authors develop two criteria to characterize these circumstances: ‘when either the plug-in is of sufficiently high quality or the open source community largely contributes to the development of the core’ (p.236). This is certainly interesting in the light of the Microsoft case. The discussion is less successful in developing the key characteristics of OSS communities (pp.226–27), which are only partly related to non-commercial incentives, and more to the different model of innovation underlying OSS communities.

            In their discussion of anti-trust, the authors tie together some of the book’s threads (on incentives for innovation, intellectual property, two-sided markets) and derive policy advice on competition policy. They propose that ‘more severe antitrust policy increases incentives to innovate if competition is not too fierce’ (p.261), and argue in favour of cross-licensing agreements involving complementary technologies (p.268). In the case of two-sided markets, the authors suggest that a more detailed merger analysis is necessary than in traditional investigations of increased market concentration (p.272).

            In general, the book is an interesting read for an audience familiar with some of the issues emerging in industries affected by information and communication technologies. It has difficulties in balancing depth (in terms of analysis) and breadth (in terms of survey character) in discussing the literature in the area. Furthermore, although the book is only recently published (2014), it already needs updating on such matters as ladder of investment theory, RPP regimes, and net neutrality. However, the book still is a good review of theoretical models not addressed in other (competing) books. Moreover, the book is challenging in delineating a research agenda for a more active government policy in network markets in times favouring laissez faire policies in these markets. I recommend the book for advanced readers at the masters level and beyond. It is less suitable for practitioners and strategists without an advanced economics background.

            Bert Sadowski
            Eindhoven University of Technology
            B.M.Sadowski@123456tue.nl
            © 2015, Bert Sadowski
            http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/08109028.2015.1070083

            References

            1. ( 1989 ) ‘ Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events ’, The Economic Journal , 99 , pp. 116 – 31 .

            2. and ( 1973 ) ‘ The telephone system as a public good: static and dynamic aspects ’, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , 4 , 1 , pp. 89 – 100 .

            3. and ( 2010 ) Industrial Organization: Markets and Strategies , Cambridge University Press , Cambridge .

            4. ( 1985 ) ‘ Clio and the economics of Qwerty ’, American Economic Review , 75 , pp. 332 – 37 .

            5. ( 1987 ) ‘ Some new standards for the economics of standardization in the information age ’ in (ed.) Economic Policy and Technological Performance , Cambridge University Press , Cambridge , pp. 206 – 39 .

            6. and ( 1994 ) ‘ Network externality: an uncommon tragedy ’, The Journal of Economic Perspectives , pp. 133 – 50 .

            7. and ( 1982 ) An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change , Harvard University Press , Cambridge .

            8. OECD ( 2002 ) Frascati Manual 2002: Proposed Standard Practice for Surveys on Research and Experimental Development , OECD , Paris .

            9. ( 1974 ) ‘ A theory of interdependent demand for a communications service ’, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science , 5 , 1 , pp. 16 – 37 .

            10. and ( 1999 ) Information Rules. A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy , Harvard Business Press , Boston MA .

            11. ( 2001 ) The Economics of Network Industries , Cambridge University Press , Cambridge .

            12. ( 1990 ) The Theory of Industrial Organization , MIT Press , Cambridge .

            13. ( 1980 ) ‘ A model of sales ’, American Economic Review , pp. 651 – 59 .

            14. ( 1990 ) Intermediate Microeconomics , W. W. Norton, New York .

            15. ( 1984 ) ‘ The cost of substitution ’, Econometrica , 52 , pp. 1085 – 116 .

            Author and article information

            Journal
            CPRO
            cpro20
            Prometheus
            Critical Studies in Innovation
            Pluto Journals
            0810-9028
            1470-1030
            March 2015
            : 33
            : 1
            : 83-85
            Affiliations
            [ a ] Eindhoven University of Technology
            Author notes
            Article
            1070083
            10.1080/08109028.2015.1070083
            68b8562f-09c0-4c4d-9576-8051c173424d
            © 2015, Bert Sadowski

            All content is freely available without charge to users or their institutions. Users are allowed to read, download, copy, distribute, print, search, or link to the full texts of the articles in this journal without asking prior permission of the publisher or the author. Articles published in the journal are distributed under a http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

            History
            Page count
            Figures: 0, Tables: 0, Equations: 0, References: 15, Pages: 3
            Categories
            Book Review
            Book Reviews

            Computer science,Arts,Social & Behavioral Sciences,Law,History,Economics

            Comments

            Comment on this article